The puzzle
All of us are now curiously thinking about the abrupt phase transition that seems to sometimes occur in the endgame of an authoritarian regime. The traditional script was: The people rise up to rebel and the strongman murders them.
When the USSR collapsed, we thought it was special: it was a defunct regime that had just lost the will to live. But for the rest, the basic rulebook stood: the people get mowed down. And sure enough, that happened in Tiananmen Square.
But now, there are an increasing number of success stories with `velvet revolutions', and one has to think more carefully about what goes in an authoritarian regime.
Conflicts beneath the surface
What appears like a monolithic regime from the outside can actually often reflect a diverse array of interests tugging in different directions. In this beautiful article by Laurence Wright on Saudi Arabia, he says:
I had begun to look at Saudi society as a collection of opposing forces: the liberals against the religious conservatives, the royal family versus democratic reformers, the unemployed against the expats, the old against the young, men against women.On that same thread, Why do protests bring down regimes? A follow up by Graeme Robertson says:
I have also read others write similarly about China (but sadly, I do not have the reference): That in the absence of freedom of speech, the regime actually has no idea about where the problems lie, and is hence hypersensitive about criticism, and about solving the problems that it thinks do matter.
While the news media focus on "the dictator", almost all authoritarian regimes are really coalitions involving a range of players with different resources, including incumbent politicians but also other elites like businessmen, bureaucrats, leaders of mass organizations like labor unions and political parties, and, of course, specialists in coercion like the military or the security forces. These elites are pivotal in deciding the fate of the regime and as long as they continue to ally themselves with the incumbent leadership, the regime is likely to remain stable. By contrast, when these elites split and some defect and decide to throw in their lot with the opposition, then the incumbents are in danger.
So where do protests come in? The problem is that in authoritarian regimes there are few sources of reliable information that can help these pivotal elites decide whom to back. Restrictions on media freedom and civil and political rights limit the amount and quality of information that is available on both the incumbents and the opposition. Moreover, the powerful incentives to pay lip service to incumbent rulers make it hard to know what to make of what information there is.
The behaviour of a jittery regime
Democracy matters in two ways. First, the regime has legitimacy. It is not worrying about a sudden upheaval that will destroy the regime. And, freedom of speech carries a steady flow of information to the regime. The UPA leadership does live in a bubble, but even they know that 8% inflation is a serious problem.
When a regime lacks legitimacy, and does not know what is going on, it is constantly fearful. It does not know what is going wrong and it can go off into extremes in trying to stave off some problems that it believes are first order. One area where this shows up is inflexible prices. To an external observer, it may be obvious that allowing price flexibility is better, but the regime is terrified about what will happen, so the price stays fixed.
Three examples
- Egypt
- In a blog post titled Garam Masala: Bread And The Life Of Egypt, Vikram Doctor writes:
I first realised how different Egypt was when I saw the bread in the street in Cairo. It was piled on low charpoy-like tables, thick rounds of freshlybaked bread, slightly scorched from the oven, a bit like tandoori rotis, but heavier.... Someone would replenish them from the bakery close by, and collect the money that people left, but nothing seemed to stop them just taking it away... the other reason why no one took the bread free was that it was so ridiculously cheap that they might as well just leave the few coins needed (in fact, buying bread seemed to be pretty much all that the piastre coins were used for). I calculated that, at that time (over 12 years back), the cost of a round of bread converted to something like three paise : something I could not imagine anything costing in any large Indian city. But this was the point: the price was unreal because a massive bread subsidy was one of the basic ways the Mubarak regime stayed in place.
- Iran
- From The regime tightens its belt and its first, in the Economist:
From top ayatollahs to the IMF, everyone agrees that spending $100 billion each year to pin down petrol, gas and electricity prices, besides the cost of staples such as flour and cooking oil, is a bad way to dispose of Iran's hydrocarbon revenues, accounting for more than 10% of GDP and encouraging waste on an epic scale. The symptoms of the malaise are legion: tea kettles simmer all day; the streets clog with recreational drivers out for a spin; lights glare because no one can be bothered to turn them off. `We can do it because we have oil,' Iranians used to tell incredulous visitors.
- China
- The outstanding price inflexibility of China is that of the exchange rate. Consider the Chinese and the Indian exchange rates of recent years:
The exchange rate is the most important price in any economy. A country that can handle a floating exchange rate is a flexible economy, one in which firms are born and die, workers move across locations and industries, and prices fluctuate. Deep and liquid markets are shock absorbers. Firms have ample equity capital, i.e. low leverage, so that they are able to absorb shocks. There is a whole configuration of institutional arrangements which are conducive to price flexibility. By and large, India fares well on these counts, particularly in the vast informal sector where there is extreme flexibility. And most of all, when things do hurt, individuals are able to express their discontent through democratic politics.
If India did not have these long-standing strengths, Governors Reddy and Subbarao would not have been able to move to a flexible exchange rate. And this exchange rate flexibility, in turn, enables an array of other economic reforms in favour of a market-based system.
Also see: The message for China from Tahrir Square by Minxin Pei in the Financial Times and The Secret Politburo Meeting Behind China's New Democracy Crackdown by Perry Link, on the New York Review of Books Blog.
Stability that is illusory
The regime change of recent years should make us think afresh about the notion of `political stability'. Democracy is always messy: demonstrations, machinations of party politics out in the open, colourful and often intemperate figures on television, elections, change in the ruling arrangement. But at a deeper level, this can be a more stable arrangement; there is no revolution at the end of the tunnel.
Similar reasoning applies in economics. Economists have always known that when prices appear to be stable, they often mask real trouble underneath. It is far better to have a small fluctuation every day, i.e. a steady flow of vol. The alternative -- of clamping down on price movements on most ordinary days -- merely yields big price movements on some days, which are far more difficult to handle.
Economic agents are not fooled by this stability on the surface. As Mark Roe says on Project Syndicate:
Even if all of the rules for finance are right, few will part with their money if they fear that an unfavorable regime change might occur during the lifetime of their investment.
More importantly, the grim stability of the type displayed by Hosni Mubarak's Egypt is oftentimes insufficient for genuine financial development. Authoritarian regimes, especially those with severe income and wealth inequality, inherently create a risk of arbitrariness, unpredictability, and instability. They are themselves arbitrary. And everyone knows that beneath the stability of the moment lurk explosive forces that can change the regime and devalue huge investments. Because financiers and savers have limited confidence in the future, such regimes can't readily build and maintain strong foundations for financial development.
Implications
This is a `capitalism and freedom' style argument: that democracy and markets interact in the double helix of modern civilisation.
Price flexibility works best when there is price flexibility in a lot of markets. If all prices were fixed, and you only freed up one, then it could easily make things worse. It is hard, crossing the hump, and reaching over to the other side where all prices are flexible. And, price flexibility goes well with democracy. Flexible prices are constantly disruptive. Every day, there are a few pockets of the economy that are really getting hurt in the creative destruction. It requires a confident regime to take these fluctuations in its stride. A jittery and illegitimate regime may be more likely to clamp down on price fluctuations since it fears these could destabilise it.
1) Democracy in name is no good. Indira Gandhi was probably as jittery as an authoritarian ruler. How long did it take democratic India to open up its markets? It did so after authoritarian China. So, democracy in name is no good. I know I will be told that in the longer term it will work out better in India and I agree with that. But, there's also the point that "in the long term we are all dead". Then there are the maoists to consider too.
ReplyDelete2) Even UPA may know that 8% inflation is bad but do you think they will implement the "free" democratic solution? Track record isn't promising.
3) The exchange rate comparison is not the full story (its only 2008 onwards). It will be interesting to see when downward movements happen in INR. I'm sure China wouldn't mind its currency moving the same as INR in the last 2-3 years.
4) "The exchange rate is the most important price in any economy." There's another price which is as important - the price of money. Why do all democracies fix it? And, why does the US democratic system fix it in such extreme ways?
My common point to all of the above is that democracy in name is no good. Kakistocracy/Oligarchy/rogue elites/closed markets can exist just as much in democracies as authoritarian regimes.
And, the track record of India as a democracy is worse than that of an authoritarian regime. Want irrefutable proof? Your handpicked examples: Egypt, China and Iran rank better on the Human Development Index than India.
This analysis holds good for a democracy like India too. The popular vote percentage does not always accurately get captured by how the seats are divided. The perceived legitimacy of a government can get shaky thanks to coalitional reality. For example, a party like the DMK has been in power through the NDA and UPA governments. Certain individuals have been ministers across governments. The manifesto on which one wins a poll has no bearing on what is implemented when in government. And, when the popular voice of the people gets suppressed, an authoritarian response is to quell the "uprising" by force. We are really large, and our size results in rebellion in portions of India that are of the size of Egypt get dismissed as irrelevant in the larger scheme of things.
ReplyDeleteWe have never had a greater sense of an undeclared emergency than we have now. The ability of the State to enter into private lives and intervene has never been greater. While we are a democracy, our people are innately tribalistic and feudal. We celebrate the powerless royalty and hold them in awe. Sections of them have assured electoral victories. Proximity to New Delhi has never mattered more than now since 1991.
We have a learning and a warning from the events in the middle East.
Not exactly sure you make a case for revolts based on fixed prices.
ReplyDeleteCan we really extrapolate price rigidity of bread in Cairo to entire Egyptian economy? Surely import prices in China changes when prices change in dollar terms - precisely by that change because exchange rate is rigid.
These revolts, it seems, are classic cases of political and economic freedoms on a broader scale.
You're being unnecessarily technical.
Hitler highjacked Democracy and brought us close to total destruction.Indira Gandhi brought monolithic regime through her emergency. Presently every thing is collapsing and people on facebook have started asking,'Do we need a revolution like Egypt'.Anything and everything could be subvereted. Only enlightened people and healthy discussion are the main source of keeping a democracy alive which is the best form of Governance the Humanity has developed.
ReplyDeleteI have to disagree with Anonymous' comments. Leaving his 'price of money' theory aside, I am baffled to see that ..."Your handpicked examples: Egypt, China and Iran rank better on the Human Development Index than India." statement can be easily handled by Democracy Index where these handpicked countries simply don't make the Democracy Index:)!!
ReplyDeleteEither the 'anonymous' wishes to live on Utopia or he is such a perfectionist he would not bear to tolerate issues such as .."democracy in name is no good...". Probably he is confusing with countries like DPR Korea and such like perhaps?
Broadwit, that was exactly my point! Those countries are not democracies and still have better HDI. Isn't it time to hold our democracy to higher levels of accountability and to aspire to the core benefits of a truer democracy?
ReplyDeleteI didn't quite understand your point about utopia and Korea.
Btw, recently, Taleb mentioned something interesting in his interview to Charlie Rose. He compared the great moderation to Egypt. I think he meant that economists in their hubris thought they could iron out the business cycle by optimizing the price of money. And, it was not very unlike the hubris of Mubarak in setting the price of bread. Both of them led to fragility and extreme events. You may disagree but a thought-provoking comparison nonetheless.